Global Risk Appetite, US Economic Policy Uncertainties and Cross-Border Capital Flow
1. Introduction
China’s 14th Five-year Plan and Long-Range Objectives through the Year 2035 call for “improving the administrative framework for cross-border capital flow and stepping up regulatory cooperation to enhance risk control and response under the conditions of opening up”. The Central Economic Work Conference held in December 2020 called for “raising risk foreseeability and preventing various risks and challenges”. Economic policy uncertainty and global capital flow volatility are major external risks facing China. For China to open up wider to the outside world and access more foreign capital, there is a need to monitor the flow and size of cross-border capital flows and develop countermeasures to cope with their unexpected sudden-stop.
Economic policy uncertainty (EPU) refers to the situation in which economic entities cannot precisely forecast whether, when and how the government will reformulate or change its current economic policies. There are several reasons for this. Countries have enacted or adjusted a large number of economic policies since the global financial crisis of 2008, making economic policy response a major external risk to their financial security and economic development (Gulen and Ion, 2016). This has been exacerbated by the sharp rise in the size and volatility of cross-border capital flow since the 1990s (Agosin and Huaita, 2011; Zhang, 2011). Macroeconomic management is made even more complex by the volatility of securities investment, which is a key component of capital flow.
This paper tests the effects of US EPU on the capital flow for emeiging economies via securities investment from the perspective of cross-border flow. An unpredictable economic environment tends to make economies less attractive to investment (Baker et al. 2016). When US economic policies become more uncertain, investments tend to shift from the US to other economies, resulting in a capital inflow into emeiging economies. A rising EPU will reduce investor risk tolerance (Pastor and Vérone si, 2013). lb avoid risk, investors search for “safe havens” and flee the uncertainties of emerging economies for safe assets such as gold and US dollar bonds (Jotikasthira et al.. 2012), causing a capital outflow from the emeiging economies.
Global risk appetite, often denoted by the VIX index as its proxy variable, reflects investors5 financial risk tolerance and attitude (Shaikh, 2019). A greater value of VIX means a smaller risk tolerance of investors. Gauvin et al. (2014) found that not only was global risk appetite a key fector in cross-border capital flow, but it could also determine the impact of other fectors on capital flow. The global risk appetite is a reflection of financial, economic and political incidents, whereas EPU is associated more with political incidents (Hartwell, 2018). While the global risk appetite has been the most prominent during the Asian Financial Crisis of 1997 and the global financial crisis of 2008, the EPU has been the most prominent during presidential elections, the September 11 terrorist attacks, and other major political incidents. Figure 1 shows the trends of US EPU, the VIX and cross-border bond funds and equity fonds from January 2004 to January 2018, revealing some correlation between US EPU and the VIX. From September 2009 to May 2011, EPU stayed at a relatively high level due to the uncertainty of whether the Federal Reserve would continue to pursue quantitative easing (QE). However, interest rate cuts unleashed sufficient liquidity to assuage market nervousness. At this time, the VIX was at the median level. During the US presidential elections in 2012 and 2016, the trends of VIX and EPU also diverged. Moreover, at different VIX values, the correlation between capital flow and EPU varies as well.
The question is how and to what extent does the EPU of developed countries, led by the US, influences cross-border capital flows for emeiging economies. Is there any heterogeneity of the effects on bond fonds and equity funds. Is the mechanism of impact subject to the impact of global risk appetite. How should emeiging economies guard against the risk of abnormal volatility in cross-border capital flows.
This paper introduces the “portfolio rebalancing effect” and the “flight to quality effect” into the theoretical model to discuss the effects of EPU on the cross-border fund investment of emerging economies. Based on the cross-border fund flow data of 21 emerging economies during 2004-2017, we use a panel threshold model to discuss the relative magnitude of both effects on different types of cross-border fond capital flow under various risk appetites. This paper’s marginal contributions may be reflected in the following aspects: Theoretically, global risk appetite and EPU are introduced into the model to discuss the relative magnitude of the “portfolio rebalancing effect” and the “flight to quality effect” under different circumstances. Empirically, unlike most studies that analyze quarterly or annual cross-border capital flows based on international balance of payment data, this paper captures the short-term change and adjustment of investor behavior on a higher-frequency dimension and at a more delicate level based on the monthly fund capital flow data of the Emeiging Portfolio Fund Research (EPFR) to enrich relevant research on cross-border capital flows. Based on the panel threshold model, we have identified specific threshold values of global risk appetite, and provide empirical evidence for safeguarding and resolving major external financial risks through fund-level and national-level heterogeneity tests.
2. Literature Review
This study is related to the following two types of literature: Driving factors of cross-border capital flow and channels for EPU to affect capital flow.
Regarding the driving factors of cross-border capital flow, Fratzscher (2012) integrated global and domestic factors into the “push・pull” factor framework, which became widely accepted. Push factors refer to external factors facing all economies and affecting investment decisions of global investors, such as global risk appetite, global interest rates, and growth rates of advanced economies (Nier et al., 2014). Pull factors highlight heterogeneous factors within individual economies, such as domestic economic growth rates, country risks, and domestic interest rates (Fratzscher, 2012; Wang, 2018). Since the global financial crisis in 2008, global risk appetites have become a focus of attention for academia, and empirical research has arrived at relatively robust and consistent conclusions, i.e. the VIX index became a proxy variable for global risk appetite, and an increase in the VIX will cause a capital outflow (Fratzscher, 2012; Ahmed and Zlate, 2014; Bruno and Shin, 2015). EPU is also a key driver of cross-border capital flow. By raising the bond risk premium, EPU nudges investors to change their domestic and foreign asset allocation strategies (Campbell et al.. 2009). Bernal et al. (2016) found that rising uncertainty could affect capital flow by influencing the financing premium between domestic and foreign markets. Chinese academics Yang and Li (2018) found that the size of China’s outward direct foreign investment (OFDI) was significantly positively correlated with China’s EPU and significantly negatively correlated with host countries, EPU. Tan et al. (2018) identified global EPU as a dominant factor of cross-border capital flow for emeiging economies. Based on the TVP-VAR model, Wang and Lu (2019) identified EPU as a key driving factor of China’s cross-border capital flows.
In terms of influencing channel, a rising EPU will increase the risk of investment in the home country or region. Based on the needs of risk mitigation and capital maintenance, investments tend to be drawn to countries or regions with a more stable macroeconomic policy environment and higher investment return. Fratzscher et al. (2018) defined the flow of capital from regions with an unstable macroeconomic environment and meagre return on assets to places with a more stable macroeconomic environment and higher return on assets as the “portfolio rebalancing effect”. Amid the rising EPU of developed countries, overseas investors will transfer fonds to emerging economies under the “portfolio rebalancing effect”. On the flipside, the rising EPU of developed countries is associated with a sharp decrease in the stock market return of emeiging economies and an increase in stock market risks (Tsai, 2017) with a negative impact on investment behavior. Zhao (2020) found that increasing external EPU would cause a capital flight from China’s stock market by influencing investor expectations. When investment uncertainty increases, international investors become less tolerant of risk, as reflected in the flight to quality effect, i.e. they disinvest from high-risk assets such as stocks and bonds in emeiging economies and shift to safe assets like the US dollar, gold and US treasury bonds (Jotikasthira et cd., 2012). Using the Panel Smooth Transition Regression (PSTR) model, Gauvin et al. (2014) investigated the non-linear effects of the US and EU’s EPU on capital flow for emerging economies, and identified global risk as a major threshold variable for the effects of EPU. However, they did not delve into the theoretical mechanisms and relative effects of the above -mentioned two mechanisms. Such a nonlinear effect is consistent with the “multiple equilibria” identified in theoretical research. Based on a theoretical model, Bacchetta et al. (2012) analyzed the multiple equilibria of investor behaviors during a period of panic, and identified investors5 risk tolerance as a key cause of multiple equilibria. From the perspective of transmission network, Li et al. (2020) discovered a sharp increase in the total spillover index of EPU under the shock of extreme events. Hence, global risk appetite could be a major variable for the mechanism of the effect of EPU. However, there has been a paucity of research papers that employ theoretical and econometric models to investigate the spillover effects of the EPU of advanced economies under different risk appetites.
3. Theoretical Mechanism
3.1 Building and Sloving of the Global Asset Portfolio Model
Following the above analysis, we constructed the “global asset portfolio model” based on the classical “mcan・variancc” theory referencing Bacchetta et al. (2008). Based on the investor expectation and decision-making model in Zhao (2020), our model investigates US economic policy uncertainty (EPU). The model assumes that international investors allocate investments between J emerging economies and G developed economies. Let ajt be the share of investments in emerging economy j during period t, and be the share of investments in advanced economy g. Then, the total share of investments in emerging economies is. Here, we consider a simple situation in which advanced and emerging economies are respectively regarded as two sets of economies with similar macroeconomic fundamentals and similar investment risks. The correlation coefficients for the internal return on assets for the two sets are pDD and pEE. respectively. Since emerging economies lag behind advanced economies in terms of financial development and institutional quality, there is a small correlation of asset return between the two sets, which is determined by their respective own fundamentals. merging economies than to advanced economies fbr the same US EPU, i.e. g(p)>f(p).
3.2 Analysis of the Global Asset Portfolio Model
By taking derivative of at in equation (9) with respect to p, we obtain the impact of US EPU on the share of emerging economies in total investment funds:
When global risk reaches a certain threshold, however, market panic will spread, and investors become less risk tolerant. Rising US EPU not only affects investors5 risk perceptions for the US, but change their risk perceptions for emerging economies as well. Less risk-tolerant investors tend to invest more in advanced economies with more resilient financial markets and a secure investment environment. At this time, international investors will adjust their risk perceptions for emerging economies more than they do for advanced economies, i.e. g(p)>f \p), which makes f (p)g(p)~g(p)f{p)<0, thus ^<0. At this time, the “flight to quality effect” outweighs the “portfolio rebalancing effect,” and rising US EPU will lead to a decrease in the share of investments in emerging economies and an outflow of cross-border capital from emerging economies.
The above mechanisms are illustrated with Figure 2.
Hence, we put forth the following hypotheses:
Hypothesis 1: When investors are more risk tolerant, rising US EPU will lead to a net inflow of cross-border capital into emerging economies, and a net capital outflow will occur only when risk tolerance is below a certain threshold.
Since equity investment is riskier than bond investment, with other external conditions being constant, equity investors are more sensitive to change in global risk, so the threshold of equity fonds should be smaller than that of bond fonds. Hence, we put forth the following assumption:
4. Data and Variable Explanation
4.1 Cross-border Capital Flow
This paper employs the EPFR database to examine the effects of US EPU on cross-border flow for emerging economies. This database tracks the monthly flow of over 9,000 bond fonds and over 18,000 equity funds, which cover some 96% of global fund assets, for a statistical analysis from different dimensions as pricing currency, registration place, and fond type. This paper collects the monthly flow data of 21 emerging economies2 3 from January 2004 to December 2017 . Jotikasthira et al. (2012) found a high degree of match between EPFR data and the international balance of payment data, lb avoid the impact of outliers, we have winsorized the capital flow data at the [1% and 99%] percentiles.
4.2 US EPU
Consistent with the capital flow data frequency, we employ the monthly indicator of US EPU calculated by Baker et al. (2016) based on a statistical analysis of news keywords such as “uncertainty” and “‘economic policy” from over 2,000 US-based newspapers. Those monthly indicators have good continuity and time-variance properties.
4.3 Global Risk Appetite
Global risk appetite is denoted by the CBOE VIX index, which is an indicator of US stock market volatility based on short-term option prices on the Standard & Poor’s 500 (S&P 500) stock index. Since VIX information is focused on the US, this paper employs investor sentiment from Baker and Wmgler5s (2007) as the proxy variable of global risk appetite for robustness.
4.4 Control Variables
This paper has controlled for global push and pull factor variables. Global push factors include: (1) the monthly M2 growth rates of the United States and the eurozone for measuring global liquidity; (2) the US federal funds rate for measuring US domestic economic situation; (3) the crude oil price index and the dollar-based MSCI world index for measuring global asset returns.
Domestic pull factors include: (1) Money market interest rates of sample economies. Rising interest rates will induce a capital inflow; (2) Stock market returns. Since the exchange rate is a key variable of capital flow (Li and Qian, 2011), we have controlled for the stock market returns of economies adjusted for exchange rates. A higher stock market return will attract more international capital inflow; (3) Capital account openness (Chinn and Ito, 2008). Emerging economies that are more open will attract more capital inflow; (4) Financial development index (Svirydzenka, 2016). Emerging economies with a higher level of financial development will face greater capital flow shocks; (5) Quarterly real GDP growth rates. Since the economic outlook is a key variable for international investment, we have controlled for the difference between real GDP growth rate with those of G4 economies (the UK, the US, Japan and the EU); (6) Government debt as a share of GDP for measuring the sovereign debt risks and economies with higher risks are less attractive to investors.
Descriptive statistics are shown in Table 1.
5. Empirical Test and Analysis of Results
Table 1: Descriptive Statistics
Variable | Number of samples | Mean value | Standard error | Min. | Max. | Data source |
Cross-border bond fund flow (%) | 3,525 | 0.7816 | 2.2377 | -11.4318 | 11.2219 | EPFR database |
Cross-border equity fund flow (%) | 3,528 | 0.2937 | 1.3017 | -22.7696 | 9.0245 | EPFR database |
US EPU | 168 | 92.7157 | 41.6772 | 37.2660 | 217.3120 | Baker et al. (2016) |
Global risk appetite | 168 | 18.5233 | 8.7086 | 10.1255 | 62.6395 | Wind database |
M2 growth rates of the US and the eurozone | 168 | 0.0047 | 0.01666 | -0.0441 | 0.0725 | Wind database and calculated by the authors. |
Federal funds rate (%) | 168 | 1.3409 | 1.7695 | 0.0664 | 5.2589 | IFS |
Crude price index yield rate (%) | 168 | 0.0044 | 0.1076 | -0.4449 | 0.2830 | Wind database |
MSCI world index yield rate (%) | 168 | 0.5111 | 4.1752 | -19.0445 | 10.9039 | MSCI official website, and calculated by the authors. |
Money market interest rate (%) | 3481 | 5.4067 | 4.5758 | 0.0207 | 80 | IFS |
MSCI economies5 index yield rate (%) | 3528 | 0.9380 | 7.9163 | -50.5052 | 44.9453 | MSCI official website, and calculated by the authors. |
Level of capital account openness | 294 | 0.2846 | 1.3323 | -1.9166 | 2.3467 | Chinn and Ito (2008) |
Financial development index | 294 | 0.4902 | 0.1579 | 0.1709 | 0.8685 | Svirydzenka (2016) |
Actual GDP quarterly growth rate (%) | 1176 | 4.5365 | 3.4988 | -13.75 | 18.641 | Wind database and calculated by the authors. |
Government debt as a share of GDP (%) | 1176 | 40.0498 | 20.5422 | 3.879 | 111.587 | IFS |
5.1 Linear Model
Where, Flowsit is the net monthly capital flow of cross-border bond and equity funds, which is denoted by the purchase or redemption of funds as a share of total assets under management. USuncertainty^ is the US EPU index, and Xi t_x is a series of control variables for capital flow with one-period lag to mitigate reverse causality. This paper has controlled for the economy fixed effect 黑 as well as year fixed effect, for a robustness test. The benchmark regression results are shown in Table 2.
Columns (1) – (3) of Table 2 are the regression results of bond fonds. Columns (4) – (6) are the regression results of equity funds. Among them, Columns (1) and (4) have not controlled for fixed effects, Columns (2) and (5) have controlled for the economy fixed effect, and Columns (3) and (6) have simultaneously controlled for the fixed effects of economy and year. The regression coefficient of US EPU is significantly positive at the 1% significance level, which indicates that US EPU is a major factor of global capital flow. When the US EPU increases, the “portfolio rebalancing effect” will outweigh the “flight to safety effect,” causing capital to flow into emerging economies. The sign of control variable is consistent with expectation. Obviously, a high degree of global risk tolerance (lower VIX value), a higher domestic stock market yield, and the higher economic growth rate will all attract international investors to invest in emerging economies.
To investigate EPU’s effects, we define the period of the 2008 global financial crisis as lasting from July 2008 to June 2009 referencing Ahmed and Zlate (2014). In this manner, our samples are divided into three parts with regression results shown in Table 3. In the precrisis era and the postcrisis recovery period, the level of global risk was lower than in the crisis era, global investors were more risk tolerant,
Table 2: Linear Regression Results
Variable | Cross-border bond funds | Cross-border equity funds | ||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | |
US EPU | 0.0066***(0.001) | 0.0064***(0.001) | 0.0072***(0.001) | 0.0059***(0.001) | 0.0058***(0.001) | 0.0043***(0.001) |
Global risk appetite (VIX) | -0.0262***(0.005) | -0.0250***(0.006) | -0.0228***(0.006) | -0.0172***(0.003) | -0.0176***(0.004) | -0.0131***(0.004) |
M2 growth rates of the US and the eurozone | -8.8932***(1.837) | -8.4142***(1.902) | -14.1728***(1.959) | -3.2640***(1.207) | -3.0945**(1.197) | -6.4539***(1.129) |
Federal funds rate | -0.0218(0.036) | -0.0405(0.046) | -0.0147(0.046) | 0.1422***(0.016) | 0.1318***(0.019) | 0.1198*** (0.020) |
Crude oil price index yield rate | 1.2207***(0.141) | 1.1752***(0.150) | 0.8200***(0.162) | -0.0097(0.126) | -0.0232(0.125) | 0.3324** (0.158) |
MSCI global index yield rate (%) | 0.1124***(0.011) | 0.1110*** (0.011) | 0.1333***(0.013) | -0.0401***(0.009) | -0.0403***(0.009) | -0.0245***(0.008) |
Money market interest rate (%) | -0.0291**(0.014) | -0.0452**(0.020) | -0.0458**(0.019) | 0.0053(0.005) | 0.0049(0.006) | 0.0060(0.006) |
MSCI economies5 index yield rate (%) | 0.0583*** (0.006) | 0.0578*** (0.006) | 0.0554***(0.006) | 0.0315***(0.005) | 0.0312***(0.005) | 0.0288***(0.005) |
Capital account openness | -0.0409(0.057) | -0.0634(0.129) | -0.0596(0.127) | 0.0128(0.013) | 0.0205(0.051) | 0.0239(0.053) |
Financial development index | -0.2519(0.382) | -4.1146*(2.053) | -3.9894* (2.020) | -0.1767(0.150) | -1.5838*(0.912) | -1.5187(0.902) |
Actual quarterly GDP growth rate (%) | 0.1031***(0.029) | 0.1100***(0.036) | 0.1101***(0.036) | 0.0002(0.006) | 0.0012(0.008) | 0.0044(0.008) |
Government debt as a share of GDP | 0.0023(0.003) | 0.0005(0.008) | 0.0015(0.008) | 0.0007(0.001) | -0.0024(0.003) | -0.0031(0.003) |
Constant term | 0.3291(0.296) | 2.3857*(1.159) | 2.6041**(1.139) | -0.0876(0.113) | 0.7521(0.515) | 0.9638*(0.553) |
Fixed effect of economy | No | Yes | Yes | No | Yes | Yes |
Fixed effect of year | No | No | Yes | No | No | Yes |
Observations | 3461 | 3461 | 3461 | 3462 | 3462 | 3462 |
R2 | 0.191 | 0.196 | 0.230 | 0.068 | 0.070 | 0.135 |
Number of countries (regions) | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 |
Note: (1) Numbers in parentheses are standard errors; (2) *, ** and *** denote significance at 10%, 5% and 1%, respectively, the same applies to the following tables.
and US EPU coefficient was significantly positive, suggesting that the “portfolio rebalancing effect” had outweighed the “flight to safety effect”. To avoid investment uncertainties in the US and seek higher investment return elsewhere, international investors ploughed capital into emerging economies. When there is a sharp increase in global risk during a crisis situation, global investors will become less risk tolerant and withdraw their capital from emerging economies and increase their holdings of US Treasury bonds and other low-risk assets.
5.2 Non-Linear Effects
Based on the above theory and research, this paper has revealed EPU’s non-linear effects on capital flow. Nier et al. (2014) identified the VIX index as an important indicator for the EPU’s spillover effects. This paper adopts a panel threshold model to test the effect of global risk appetite on cross-border capital flow. This model was introduced by Hansen (1999).
Table 3: Regression Results before and after the Global Financial Crisis
Variable | Cross-border bond funds | Cross-border equity funds | ||||
(1)Before crisis | ⑵ During crisis | (3) After crisis | (4) Before crisis | (5) During crisis | (6) After crisis | |
US EPU | 0.0093***(0.002) | -0.1330***(0.013) | 0.0122***(0.001) | 0.0221***(0.002) | -0.0176***(0.003) | 0.0058***(0.000) |
Control variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fixed effect of economy | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Fixed effect of year | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Observations | 1084 | 231 | 2104 | 1085 | 231 | 2104 |
R2 | 0.298 | 0.972 | 0.378 | 0.150 | 0.825 | 0.367 |
Number of countries (regions) | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 |
Table 4 shows the testing results of the threshold effect. Dual thresholds exist for both bond fonds and equity fluids, and the threshold value of equity funds is smaller than that of bond fonds. Hence, Hypothesis 2 is verified.
Table 5 shows the total sample regression results. Different value intervals of the VIX index have changed the direction and magnitude of EPU5s impact on capital flow. This suggests that as the indicator for capital availability and global risk appetite, the VIX index not only affects capital flow by itself, but also determines other push factors5 effects on capital flow. As can be seen from the results of Column (1), for bond funds, when VIX is below the threshold value of 29.916, EPU will have a positive effect on capital flow, i.e. the “portfolio rebalancing effect” will dominate as long as risks are within control, but beyond a certain threshold, rising US EPU will cause capital to flow out of emerging economies, which is consistent with the theoretical model laid out in the previous section. As can be seen from the results of Column (3),
Table 4: Test of Threshold Effect
Place of fund registration | Bond funds | Equity funds | |||||
Null hypothesis | F statistic | p value | Threshold value | F statistic | p value | Threshold value | |
Total samples | I | 351.07*** | 0.0000 | 17.705 | 136.77** | 0.0180 | 12.471 |
II | 78.50*** | 0.0020 | 17.705, 29.916 | 115.53*** | 0.0000 | 12.471, 22.199 | |
III | 51.91 | 0.9080 | – | 74.80 | 0.7740 | – |
Notes: null hypotheses I, II and III indicate the non-existence of threshold value, the existence of one threshold value, and the existence of two threshold values.
Table 5: Results of the Panel Threshold Model Regression
Variable | Bond funds | Equity funds | ||
(1) Total samples | .(2)Exclusion of offshore financial centers | (3) Total samples | .H) Exclusion of offshore financial centers | |
US economic uncertainty | 0.0038*** | 0.0044*** | 0.0056*** | 0.0059*** |
g<为) | (0.001) | (0.001) | (0.001) | (0.001) |
US economic uncertainty | 0.0142*** | 0.0145*** | 0.0127*** | 0.0134*** |
^<VIX<71) | (0.001) | (0.001) | (0.001) | (0.001) |
US economic uncertainty | -0.0098*** | -0.0093*** | 0.0036*** | 0.0033*** |
g F | (0.001) | (0.001) | (0.001) | (0.001) |
Control variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Observations | 2,919 | 2,641 | 2,919 | 2,641 |
R2 | 0.277 | 0.277 | 0.121 | 0.123 |
Number of countries (regions) | 21 | 19 | 21 | 19 |
for equity funds, the regression coefficient remains significantly positive when VIX is above 22.199, but the value is significantly smaller than that when VIX is smaller, lb exclude the impact of samples with more volatile capital flows, the conclusions are still true after excluding China’s Hong Kong and the Republic of Singapore.
To fiirther verify the above-mentioned hypothesis that the “threshold value of equity fonds is below that of bond fiinds,” we gradually added three-month data on the basis of data from January 2004 to December 2009, and the results are shown in Figure 4. Horizontal axis is the number of quarters added. Vertical axis is the estimated threshold value. Solid line denotes the threshold value of bond fonds. Dotted line is the threshold value of equity fonds. Both the first and second threshold values of bond fonds are substantially higher than those of equity funds. Hypothesis 2 is thus verified.
5.3 Heterogeneity Analysis
5.3.1 Fund type heterogeneity analysis
This paper further tests the heterogeneous effects of US EPU on fond types.3 Table 6 reports the regression results of bond fonds4 The coefficient of proactively managed funds turns from positive to negative after the threshold value exceeds 29.9164, and passive fonds are free from the threshold effect with a significantly negative regression coefficient. The same threshold value is adopted for ETF fluids, mutual funds, retail investor fonds and institutional investor fonds. However, under a high VIX index, the absolute value of regression coefficient of ETF fonds is greater than that of mutual fonds, and the absolute value of regression coefficient of retail investor funds is greater than that of institutional investors. The above results indicate that in the bond fond category, passively managed fonds, ETF fonds and retail investor fonds are more risk averse, causing capital flow to respond more to US EPU.
Table 7 reports regression results of equity funds. The threshold values of proactively managed
Pakistan is excluded due to the lack of categorized fund data.
In the interest of length, the result of threshold effect test is not presented here but available upon request. The same below.
Table 6: Regression Results of the Heterogeneous Characteristics of Bond Funds
Variable | (1)Active funds | (2) Passive funds | (3)ETF funds | (4) Mutual funds | (5)Retail investor funds | ..⑹Institutional investor funds |
US EPU | 0.0285***(0.001) | 0.0126**(0.005) | 0.0215***(0.001) | 0.0238***(0.001) | 0.0195***(0.001) | |
US EPU (71<EZX<.2) | 0.0080***(0.001) | 0.0066***(0.001) | 0.0066***(0.001) | 0.0064***(0.001) | ||
US EPUg F | -0.0196***(0.001) | -0.0201***(0.001) | -0.0253***(0.002) | -0.0184***(0.001) | ||
US EPU(吹由) | -0.0612***(0.007) | |||||
US EPU | -0.0068***(0.002) | |||||
Control variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Observations | 2,500 | 2,200 | 2,200 | 2,540 | 2,540 | 2,540 |
R2 | 0.351 | 0.117 | 0.306 | 0.343 | 0.320 | 0.292 |
Number of countries (regions) | 20 | 20 | 20 | 20 | 20 | 20 |
Notes: Since passive funds demonstrate no threshold effect, we performed the estimation using Model (11).
Table 7: Regression Results of the Heterogeneous Characteristics of Equity Funds
Variable | (1)Active funds | (2)Passive funds | (3)ETF funds | (4) Mutual funds | (5)Retail investor funds | (6)Institutional investor funds |
US EPU | 0.0008* | 0.0002 | 0.0011** | 0.0045*** | -0.0012*** | 0.0045*** |
(0.000) | (0.001) | (0.000) | (0.002) | (0.000) | (0.001) | |
US EPU (71<EZX<.2) | 0.0128***(0.002) | 0.0136***(0.001) | ||||
US EPUg F | -0.0100***(0.002) | 0.0032**(0.001) | ||||
US EPU | -0.0029*** | -0.0024*** | -0.0149*** | -0.0075*** | ||
(吹由) | (0.001) | (0.000) | (0.002) | (0.001) | ||
Control variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Observations | 2,520 | 2,200 | 2,540 | 2,200 | 2,540 | 2,540 |
R2 | 0.239 | 0.227 | 0.230 | 0.194 | 0.258 | 0.233 |
Number of countries (regions) | 20 | 20 | 20 | 20 | 20 | 20 |
fonds and ETF funds are 19.2275 and 20.6432, respectively, which are below the threshold values of passively managed funds and mutual funds (31.9295 and 29.9164). While rising US EPU has led retail investors to flee emerging economies, institutional investors will increase equity fund investments in emerging economies. The implication is that proactively managed fonds, ETF fonds and retail investor fonds are more risk averse and sensitive to global risks.
Except for the differences of passive bond fonds, the above findings are consistent with Brandâo-Marques et al. (2015). Since passive fonds are usually pegged to a specific index without pursuing excess return to beat market performance, their fund managers are not motivated to closely follow market situations and global risks. Hence, passive funds are less risk sensitive than proactively managed funds.
With their flexibility and liquidity, ETF fonds have attracted a great deal of profit-seeking short-term investments (Sushko and Turner, 2018). Compared with such fiindamental factors as growth prospects, short-term investors are more sensitive to changing risks. Without professional risk management competence and investment experience, retail investors are more sensitive to changing global risks compared with institutional investors. Rising US EPU will cause them to flee emerging economies.
5.3.2 Heterogeneity analysis at the level of economies
To investigate how the capital flow of various economies is influenced by such indicators as capital account openness, financial market development, and economic growth rate, we divided the samples into three groups by their medians. Regression results of cross-border bond fiinds are shown in Table 8, and those of cross-border equity funds are shown in Table 9. For bond funds, the thresholds for the coefficient of US EPU to turn from positive to negative are all 29.9164. After VIX crosses this threshold, countries (regions) with higher financial development and higher GDP growth have smaller absolute values of regression coefficients. This indicates that the level of financial development and GDP growth have somewhat eased EPU’s negative capital flow effects. The same conclusion can be drawn for equity funds.
5.4 Robustness Test
5.4.1 Replacing the EPUvariable
We performed a regression analysis using global EPU as the instrumental variable for US EPU. Except for the negative correlation between bond funds and global EPU under the low VIX value, there is no significant change in the sign and magnitude of threshold effect and regression coefficient, i.e. our conclusions are robust.
5.4.2 Replacing the risk appetite variable
To test the sensitivity of regression results of the risk appetite, we replaced VIX with investor
Table 8: Heterogeneity Regression Results for Bond Funds at the Country (Region) Level
Variable | Capital account openness | Financial market development | GDP growth rate | |||
(1) Low | (2) High | (3) Low | (4) High | (5) Low | ⑹ High | |
US EPU g</i) | 0.0045***(0.001) | 0.0043**(0.001) | 0.0064***(0.001) | 0.0024(0.002) | 0.0276***(0.003) | 0.0044(0.002) |
US EPU (71<RZX<.2) | 0.0152***(0.002) | 0.0135***(0.002) | 0.0059***(0.001) | 0.0161***(0.003) | ||
US EPU g F | -0.0106***(0.002) | -0.0095***(0.002) | -0.0182***(0.001) | -0.0098***(0.003) | ||
US EPU(吹由) | -0.0147***(0.002) | -0.0152***(0.001) | ||||
Control variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Observations | 1,668 | 1,251 | 1,668 | 1,251 | 1,807 | 1,112 |
R2 | 0.285 | 0.278 | 0.254 | 0.336 | 0.289 | 0.302 |
Number of countries (regions) | 12 | 9 | 12 | 9 | 13 | 8 |
In the interest of length, robustness test results are not shown but available from the authors upon request.
Table 9: Heterogeneity Regression Results for Equity Funds at the Country (Region) Level
Variable | Capital account openness | Financial market development | GDP growth rate | |||
(1) Low | ⑵ High | (3) Low | (4) High | (5) Low | ⑹ High | |
US EPU | 0.0067***(0.001) | 0.0043***(0.001) | 0.0065***(0.001) | |||
US EPU (71<EZY<.2) | 0.0144***(0.002) | 0.0110***(0.002) | ||||
US EPUg>为) | 0.0050***(0.001) | 0.0026(0.002) | ||||
US EPUgW | -0.0027*(0.001) | |||||
US EPU | 0.0066***(0.001) | 0.0056***(0.001) | 0.0064***(0.001) | |||
Control variable | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Observations | 1,668 | 1,251 | 1,668 | 1,251 | 1,807 | 1,112 |
R2 | 0.146 | 0.099 | 0.092 | 0.096 | 0.064 | 0.091 |
Number of countries (regions) | 12 | 9 | 12 | 9 | 13 | 8 |
Notes: Since no threshold effect is demonstrated in Columns (4) – (6), we performed the estimation using Model (11).
sentiment from Baker and Wurgler’s (2007) for a regression analysis. The sign of US EPU is consistent with benchmark regression, i.e. our conclusions are still valid using another method for measuring the critical threshold variable.
5.4.3 Controlling for the EPU of economies with capital inflows
We included in the control variables on EPU index for economies with capital inflows to exclude the EPU impact of such economies, and the regression results remain robust.
6. Conclusions and Policy Recommendations
With the cross-border portfolio capital flows of emerging economies as the subject of research, this paper created a theoretical model to explain the effects of US EPU on cross-border capital flow, and tested the theoretical model with the monthly cross-border fund data of 2004-2017. In the panel threshold model, we identified the thresholds of global risk appetite as the threshold variable. According to our analysis, when the VIX index is below the threshold, rising US EPU will cause securities investment to flow into emeiging economies, i.e. the “portfolio rebalancing effect” holds sway; when VIX exceeds the threshold, rising US EPU will cause international capital to exit emeiging economies. After classifying fund types, we found that proactively managed fonds, ETF funds and retail investor funds were more sensitive to global risk appetites, and that increasing domestic GDP growth rates and financial market development were conducive to easing the negative impact of rising EPU on capital flow.
We put forth the following policy recommendations for emeiging economies to cushion the capital flow effects of EPU.
First, global risk appetite and the EPU of countries have a major influence on cross-border capital flow. To minimize the negative impact of a worsening financial environment, countries should increase their observation and monitoring of the external financial environment and make targeted responses to different types of global risk shocks.
Second, supervision of cross-border capital flow should focus on both the aggregate amount and the structural change of the cross-border capital flow. Sudden and significant short-term capital flows via securities investment will affect a country’s asset prices and financial stability. Hence, countries should closely monitor their capital flow, pay attention to proactively managed funds, ETF fonds and retail investor funds that are more sensitive to global financial situations, and improve market monitoring, early warning and response mechanisms.
Lastly, countries should improve their economic development while opening up their capital markets to maintain sound economic growth rates at home. They should develop and improve their domestic financial markets to attract cross-border capital. In the interest of global financial health and stability, they should also improve their monetary policy and macro-prudential policy, maintain policy transparency, reduce the impact of domestic policy uncertainty, step up international economic policy coordination, and prevent systemic financial risk.